Jump to content

Minimum wage: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
ClueBot (talk | contribs)
m Reverting possible vandalism by 194.66.199.91 to version by 24.91.190.195. False positive? Report it. Thanks, ClueBot. (749751) (Bot)
Line 3: Line 3:


==Background==
==Background==
Minimum wages were first proposed as a way to control the proliferation of [[sweat shop]]s in manufacturing industries. The sweat shops employed large numbers of women and young workers, paying them what were considered to be substandard wages. The sweatshop owners were thought to have unfair bargaining power over their workers, and a minimum wage was proposed as a means to make them pay "fairly." Over time, the focus changed to helping people, especially families, become more self sufficient. Today, minimum wage laws cover workers in most low-paid fields of employment.<ref name='Neumark'>{{cite book | last = Neumark | first = David | authorlink = | coauthors = William L. Wascher | title = Minimum Wages | publisher = The MIT Press | date = 2008 | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | pages = | url = http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=11659 | doi = | id = | isbn = 978-0-262-14102-4 }}</ref>
Your mom has a flippen FAT ass. that is why she has to get the minimum wage... Minimum wages were first proposed as a way to control the proliferation of [[sweat shop]]s in manufacturing industries. The sweat shops employed large numbers of women and young workers, paying them what were considered to be substandard wages. The sweatshop owners were thought to have unfair bargaining power over their workers, and a minimum wage was proposed as a means to make them pay "fairly." Over time, the focus changed to helping people, especially families, become more self sufficient. Today, minimum wage laws cover workers in most low-paid fields of employment.<ref name='Neumark'>{{cite book | last = Neumark | first = David | authorlink = | coauthors = William L. Wascher | title = Minimum Wages | publisher = The MIT Press | date = 2008 | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | pages = | url = http://mitpress.mit.edu/catalog/item/default.asp?ttype=2&tid=11659 | doi = | id = | isbn = 978-0-262-14102-4 }}</ref>


The minimum wage has a strong social appeal, rooted in concern about the ability of markets to provide income equity for the least able members of the work force. An obvious solution to this concern is to redefine the wage structure politically to achieve a socially preferable distribution of income. Thus, minimum wage laws have usually been judged against the criterion of reducing poverty.<ref name='Palgrave1987'>{{cite book | last = Eatwell | first = John, Ed. | authorlink = | coauthors = Murray Milgate, Peter Newman | title = The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics | publisher = The Macmillan Press Limited | date = 1987 | location = London | pages = 476–478 | url = | doi = | id = | isbn = 0-333-37235-2 }}</ref>
The minimum wage has a strong social appeal, rooted in concern about the ability of markets to provide income equity for the least able members of the work force. An obvious solution to this concern is to redefine the wage structure politically to achieve a socially preferable distribution of income. Thus, minimum wage laws have usually been judged against the criterion of reducing poverty.<ref name='Palgrave1987'>{{cite book | last = Eatwell | first = John, Ed. | authorlink = | coauthors = Murray Milgate, Peter Newman | title = The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics | publisher = The Macmillan Press Limited | date = 1987 | location = London | pages = 476–478 | url = | doi = | id = | isbn = 0-333-37235-2 }}</ref>

Revision as of 07:38, 6 August 2009

A minimum wage is the lowest hourly, daily or monthly wage that employers may legally pay to employees or workers. Equivalently, it is the lowest wage at which workers may sell their labor. Although minimum wage laws are in effect in a great many jurisdictions, there are differences of opinion about the benefits and drawbacks of a minimum wage. Supporters of the minimum wage say that it increases the standard of living of workers and reduces poverty.[1] Opponents say that if it is high enough to be effective, it increases unemployment, particularly among workers with very low productivity due to inexperience or handicap, thereby harming lesser skilled workers to the benefit of better skilled workers.[2]

Background

Your mom has a flippen FAT ass. that is why she has to get the minimum wage... Minimum wages were first proposed as a way to control the proliferation of sweat shops in manufacturing industries. The sweat shops employed large numbers of women and young workers, paying them what were considered to be substandard wages. The sweatshop owners were thought to have unfair bargaining power over their workers, and a minimum wage was proposed as a means to make them pay "fairly." Over time, the focus changed to helping people, especially families, become more self sufficient. Today, minimum wage laws cover workers in most low-paid fields of employment.[3]

The minimum wage has a strong social appeal, rooted in concern about the ability of markets to provide income equity for the least able members of the work force. An obvious solution to this concern is to redefine the wage structure politically to achieve a socially preferable distribution of income. Thus, minimum wage laws have usually been judged against the criterion of reducing poverty.[4]

Though the goals of the minimum wage are widely accepted as right and proper, there is great disagreement as to whether it is effective in attaining its goals. From the time of their introduction, minimum wage laws have been highly controversial politically, and have received much less support from economists than from the general public. Despite decades of experience and economic research, debates about the costs and benefits of minimum wages continue even today.[3]

The classic exposition of the minimum wage's shortcomings in reducing poverty was provided by George Stigler in 1946:

  • Employment may fall more than in proportion to the wage increase, thereby reducing overall earnings;
  • As uncovered sectors of the economy absorb workers released from the covered sectors, the decrease in wages in the uncovered sectors may exceed the increase in wages in the covered ones;
  • The impact of the minimum wage on family income distribution may be negative unless the fewer but better jobs are allocated to members of needy families rather than to, for example, teenagers from families not in poverty;
  • The legal restriction that employers cannot pay less than a legislated wage is equivalent to the legal restriction that workers cannot work at all in the protected sector unless they can find employers willing to hire them at that wage.[4]

Direct empirical studies indicate that anti-poverty effects in the U.S. would be quite modest, even if there were no unemployment effects. Very few low-wage workers come from families in poverty. Those primarily affected by minimum wage laws are teenagers and low-skilled adult females who work part time, and any wage rate effects on their income is strictly proportional to the hours of work they are offered. So, if market outcomes for low-skilled families are to be supplemented in a socially satisfactory way, factors other than wage rates must also be considered. Employment opportunities and the factors that limit labor market participation must be considered as well.[4] Economist Thomas Sowell has also argued that regardless of custom or law, the real minimum wage is always zero, and zero is what some people would receive if they fail to find jobs when they try to enter the workforce, or they lose the jobs they already have.[5]

Minimum wage law

First enacted in Australia and New Zealand in the late nineteenth century,[6] there is now legislation regarding minimum wage fixing in more than 90% of countries.[7]

Minimum wage laws vary greatly across many different jurisdictions, not only in setting a particular amount of money (e.g. US$7.25 per hour under U.S. Federal law, $8.55 in the U.S. state of Washington,[8] and £5.73 (for those aged 22+) in the United Kingdom[9]), but also in terms of which pay period (e.g. Russia and China set monthly minimums) or the scope of coverage. Some jurisdictions allow employers to count tips given to their workers as credit towards the minimum wage level.

Informal minimum wages

Sometimes a minimum wage exists without a law. Custom and extra-legal pressures from governments or labor unions can produce a de facto minimum wage. So can international public opinion, by pressuring multinational companies to pay Third World workers wages usually found in more industrialized countries. The latter situation in Southeast Asia and Latin America has been publicized in recent years, but it existed with companies in West Africa in the middle of the twentieth century.[5]

Economics of the minimum wage

Simple supply and demand

A mainstream economics analysis of supply and demand implies that by mandating a price floor above the equilibrium wage, minimum wage laws should cause unemployment. This is because a greater number of workers are willing to work at the higher wage while a smaller numbers of jobs will be available at the higher wage. Companies can be more selective in those whom they employ thus the least skilled and inexperienced will typically be excluded.

According to the model shown in nearly all introductory textbooks on economics, increasing the minimum wage decreases the employment of minimum-wage workers.[10] One such textbook says:

"If a higher minimum wage increases the wage rates of unskilled workers above the level that would be established by market forces, the quantity of unskilled workers employed will fall. The minimum wage will price the services of the least productive (and therefore lowest-wage) workers out of the market. ... The direct results of minimum wage legislation are clearly mixed. Some workers, most likely those whose previous wages were closest to the minimum, will enjoy higher wages. Other, particularly those with the lowest prelegislation wage rates, will be unable to find work. They will be pushed into the ranks of the unemployed or out of the labor force."[11]

It illustrates the point with a supply and demand diagram similar to the one below.

Graph of Labor Market
Graph of Labor Market

It is assumed that workers are willing to labor for more hours if paid a higher wage. Economists graph this relationship with the wage on the vertical axis and the quantity (hours) of labor supplied on the horizontal axis. Since higher wages increase the quantity supplied, the supply of labor curve is upward sloping, and is shown as a line moving up and to the right.[12]

A firm's cost is a function of the wage rate. It is assumed that the higher the wage, the fewer hours an employer will demand of an employee. This is because, as the wage rate rises, it becomes more expensive for firms to hire workers and so firms hire fewer workers (or hire them for fewer hours). The demand of labor curve is therefore shown as a line moving down and to the right.[12]

Combining the demand and supply curves for labor allows us to examine the effect of the minimum wage. We will start by assuming that the supply and demand curves for labor will not change as a result of raising the minimum wage. This assumption has been questioned. If no minimum wage is in place, workers and employers will continue to adjust the quantity of labor supplied according to price until the quantity of labor demanded is equal to the quantity of labor supplied, reaching equilibrium price, where the supply and demand curves intersect. Minimum wage behaves as a classical price floor on labor. Standard theory says that, if set above the equilibrium price, more labor will be willing to be provided by workers than will be demanded by employers, creating a surplus of labor i.e. unemployment.[12]

In other words, the simplest and most basic economics says this about commodities like labor (and wheat, for example): Artificially raising the price of the commodity tends to cause the supply of it to increase and the demand for it to lessen. The result is a surplus of the commodity. When there is a wheat surplus, the government buys it. Since the government doesn't hire surplus labor, the labor surplus takes the form of unemployment, which tends to be higher with minimum wage laws than without them.[5]

So the basic theory says that raising the minimum wage helps workers whose wages are raised, and hurts people who are not hired (or lose their jobs) because companies cut back on employment. But the situation is much more complicated than the basic theory can account for.

One complicating factor is possible monopsony in the labor market, whereby the individual employer has some market power in determining wages paid. Thus it is at least theoretically possible that the minimum wage may boost employment. Though single employer market power is unlikely to exist in most labor markets in the sense of the traditional 'company town,' asymmetric information, imperfect mobility, and the 'personal' element of the labor transaction give some degree of wage-setting power to most firms.[13]

Standard theory criticism

The argument that minimum wages decrease employment is based on a standard supply and demand model of the labor market. A number of economists (for example Pierangelo Garegnani[14] and Robert L. Vienneau[15]), building on the work of Piero Sraffa, argue that that model, even given all its assumptions, is logically incoherent. Michael Anyadike-Danes and Wyne Godley [16] argue, based on simulation results, that little of the empirical work done with the textbook model constitutes a potentially falsifying test, and, consequently, empirical evidence hardly exists for that model. Graham White [17] argues, partially on the basis of Sraffianism, that the policy of increased labor market flexibility, including the reduction of minimum wages, does not have an "intellectually coherent" argument in economic theory.

Gary Fields, Professor of Labor Economics and Economics at Cornell University, argues that the standard "textbook model" for the minimum wage is "ambiguous", and that the standard theoretical arguments incorrectly measure only a one-sector market. Fields says a two-sector market, where "the self-employed, service workers, and farm workers are typically excluded from minimum-wage coverage… [and with] one sector with minimum-wage coverage and the other without it [and possible mobility between the two]," is the basis for better analysis. Through this model, Fields shows the typical theoretical argument to be ambiguous and says "the predictions derived from the textbook model definitely do not carry over to the two-sector case. Therefore, since a non-covered sector exists nearly everywhere, the predictions of the textbook model simply cannot be relied on."[18]

An alternate view of the labor market has low-wage labor markets characterized as monopsonistic competition wherein buyers (employers) have significantly more market power than do sellers (workers). This monopsony could be a result of intentional collusion between employers, or naturalistic factors such as segmented markets, information costs, imperfect mobility and the 'personal' element of labor markets. In such a case the diagram above would not yield the quantity of labor clearing and the wage rate. This is because while the upward sloping aggregate labor supply would remain unchanged, instead of using the downward labor demand curve shown in the diagram above, monopsonistic employers would use a steeper downward sloping curve corresponding to marginal expenditures to yield the intersection with the supply curve resulting in a wage rate lower than would be the case under competition. Also, the amount of labor sold would also be lower than the competitive optimal allocation.

Such a case is a type of market failure and results in workers being paid less than their marginal value. Under the monopsonistic assumption, an appropriately set minimum wage could increase both wages and employment, with the optimal level being equal to the marginal productivity of labor.[19] This view emphasizes the role of minimum wages as a market regulation policy akin to antitrust policies, as opposed to an illusory "free lunch" for low-wage workers.

Another reason minimum wage may not affect employment in certain industries is that the demand for the product the employees produce is highly inelastic;[20] For example, if management is forced to increase wages, management can pass on the increase in wage to consumers in the form of higher prices. Since demand for the product is highly inelastic, consumers continue to buy the product at the higher price and so the manager is not forced to lay off workers.

Three other possible reasons minimum wages do not affect employment were suggested by Alan Blinder: higher wages may reduce turnover, and hence training costs; raising the minimum wage may "render moot" the potential problem of recruiting workers at a higher wage than current workers; and minimum wage workers might represent such a small proportion of a business's cost that the increase is too small to matter. He admits that he does not know if these are correct, but argues that "the list demonstrates that one can accept the new empirical findings and still be a card-carrying economist."[21]

Debate over consequences

Various groups have great ideological, political, financial, and emotional investments in issues surrounding minimum wage laws. For example, agencies that administer the laws have a vested interest in showing that "their" laws do not create unemployment. So do labor unions, whose members' jobs are protected by minimum wage laws. The presence of these powerful groups and factors means that the debate on the issue is not always based on dispassionate analysis. Not only that, but it is extraordinarily difficult to separate the effects of minimum wage from all the other variables that affect employment.[5]

On the other side of the issue, low-wage employers such as restaurants finance the Employment Policies Institute, which has released numerous studies opposing the minimum wage.[22]

The following table summarizes the arguments made by those for and against minimum wage laws:

Template:MultiCol

Arguments in favor of Minimum Wage Laws

Supporters of the minimum wage claim it has these effects:

  • Increases the standard of living for the poorest and most vulnerable class in society and raises average.[1]
  • Motivates and encourages employee to work harder. (Contrast with welfare transfer payments.)[23]
  • Does not have budget consequence on government. "Neither taxes nor public sector borrowing requirements rise." (Contrast with negative income taxes such as the EITC.)[23]
  • Minimum wage is administratively simple; workers only need to report violations of wages less than minimum, minimizing a need for a large enforcement agency.[23]
  • Stimulates consumption, by putting more money in the hands of low-income people who spend their entire paychecks.[1]
  • Increases the work ethic of those who earn very little, as employers demand more return from the higher cost of hiring these employees.[1]
  • Decreases the cost of government social welfare programs by increasing incomes for the lowest-paid.[1]
  • Does not have a substantial effect on unemployment compared to most other economic factors [24], and so does not put any extra pressure on welfare systems.
  • A study of U.S. states showed that businesses' annual and average payrolls grow faster and employment grew at a faster rate in states with a minimum wage.[25] The study showed a correlation, but did not claim to prove causation.
  • Helps small businesses as well as big businesses.[26]

| class="col-break " |

Arguments against Minimum Wage Laws

Opponents of the minimum wage claim it has these effects:

  • Excludes low cost competitors from labour markets, hampers firms in reducing wage costs during trade downturns (etc.), generates various industrial-economic inefficiencies as well as unemployment, poverty, and price rises, and generally dysfunctions as basically a special form of political-economic protectionism – the labour market equivalent or analogue of such things as tariff barriers to low cost imports.[27]
  • Hurts small business more than large business. [28]
  • Lowers competitiveness among businesses[29]
  • Reduces quantity demanded of workers. This may manifest itself through a reduction in the number of hours worked by individuals, or through a reduction in the number of jobs.[30][31]
  • Reduces profit margins of business owners employing minimum wage workers, thus encouraging a move to businesses that do not employ low-skill workers.[32]
  • Businesses try to compensate for the decrease in profit by simply raising the prices of the goods being sold thus causing inflation and increasing the costs of goods and services produced. [33][34]
  • Does not improve the situation of those in poverty, it benefits some at the expense of the poorest and least productive.[35]
  • Is a limit on the freedom of both employers and employees, and can result in the exclusion of certain groups from the labor force. For example, during the apartheid era in South Africa, white trade unions lobbied for the introduction of minimum wage laws so as to exclude black workers from the labor market. By preventing black workers from selling their labor for less than white workers, the black workers were prevented from competing for jobs held by whites.[36]
  • Businesses spend less on training their employees.[37]
  • Is less effective than other methods (e.g. the Earned Income Tax Credit) at reducing poverty, and is more damaging to businesses than those other methods.[37]
  • Discourages further education among the poor by enticing people to enter the job market.[37]
  • Causes outsourcing and loss of domestic manfucturing jobs to other countries.[38]

Template:EndMultiCol

Today, the International Labour Organization (ILO)[7] and the OECD[24] do not consider that the minimum wage can be directly linked to unemployment in countries which have suffered job losses. Although strongly opposed by both the business community and the Conservative Party when introduced in 1999, the minimum wage introduced in the UK is no longer controversial and the Conservatives reversed their opposition in 2000.[39] A review of its effects found no discernible impact on employment levels.[40]

Since the introduction of a national minimum wage in the UK in 1999, its effects on employment were subject to extensive research and observation by the Low Pay Commission. The Low Pay Commission found that, rather than make employees redundant, employers have reduced their rate of hiring, reduced staff hours, increased prices, and have found ways to cause current workers to be more productive (especially service companies).[41] Neither trade unions nor employer organizations contest the minimum wage, although the latter had especially done so heavily until 1999.

Empirical studies

Economists disagree as to the measurable impact of minimum wages in the 'real world'. This disagreement usually takes the form of competing empirical tests of the elasticities of demand and supply in labor markets and the degree to which markets differ from the efficiency that models of perfect competition predict.

Economists have done empirical studies on numerous aspects of the minimum wage, prominently including:[3]

  • Employment effects, the most frequently studied aspect
  • Effects on the distribution of wages and earnings among low-paid and higher-paid workers
  • Effects on the distribution of incomes among low-income and higher-income families
  • Effects on the skills of workers through job training and the deferring of work to acquire education
  • Effects on prices and profits

Until the mid-1990s, a strong consensus existed among economists, both conservative and liberal, that the minimum wage reduced employment, especially among younger and low-skill workers.[10] In addition to the basic supply-demand intuition, there were a number of empirical studies that supported this view. For example, Gramlich (1976) found that many of the benefits went to higher income families, and in particular that teenagers were made worse off by the unemployment associated with the minimum wage.[42]

Brown et al. (1983) note that time series studies to that point had found that for a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage, there was a decrease in teenage employment of 1-3 percent. However, for the effect on the teenage unemployment rate, the studies exhibited wider variation in their estimates, from zero to over 3 percent. In contrast to the simple supply/demand figure above, it was commonly found that teenagers withdrew from the labor force in response to the minimum wage, which produced the possibility of equal reductions in the supply as well as the demand for labor at a higher minimum wage and hence no impact on the unemployment rate. Using a variety of specifications of the employment and unemployment equations (using ordinary least squares vs. generalized least squares regression procedures, and linear vs. logarithmic specifications), they found that a 10 percent increase in the minimum wage caused a 1 percent decrease in teenage employment, and no change in the teenage unemployment rate. The study also found a small, but statistically significant, increase in unemployment for adults aged 20–24.[43]

Wellington (1991) updated Brown et al.'s research with data through 1986 to provide new estimates encompassing a period when the real (i.e., inflation-adjusted) value of the minimum wage was declining, due to the fact that it had not increased since 1981. She found that a 10% increase in the minimum wage decreased teenage employment by 0.6 percentage points, with no effect on either the teen or young adult unemployment rates.[44]

Some research suggests that the unemployment effects of small minimum wage increases are dominated by other factors. [8] In Florida, where voters approved an increase in 2004, a follow-up comprehensive study confirms a strong economy with increased employment above previous years in Florida and better than in the U.S. as a whole.[9]

Card and Krueger

In 1992, the minimum wage in New Jersey increased from $4.25 to $5.05 per hour (an 18.8% increase) while the adjacent state of Pennsylvania remained at $4.25. David Card and Alan Krueger gathered information on fast food restaurants in New Jersey and eastern Pennsylvania in an attempt to see what effect this increase had on employment within New Jersey. Basic economic theory would have implied that relative employment should have decreased in New Jersey. Card and Krueger surveyed employers before the April 1992 New Jersey increase, and again in November-December 1992, asking managers for data on the full-time equivalent staff level of their restaurants both times.[45] Based on the employers' responses, the authors concluded that the increase in the minimum wage increased employment in the New Jersey restaurants.[46]

Card and Krueger expanded on this initial article in their 1995 book Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage (ISBN 0-691-04823-1). They argued that the negative employment effects of minimum wage laws are minimal if not non-existent. For example, they look at the 1992 increase in New Jersey's minimum wage, the 1988 rise in California's minimum wage, and the 1990-91 increases in the federal minimum wage. In addition to their own findings, they reanalyzed earlier studies with updated data, generally finding that the older results of a negative employment effect did not hold up in the larger datasets.

Critics, however, argue that their research was flawed.[47] Subsequent attempts to verify the claims requested payroll cards from employers to verify employment, and found that the minimum wage increases were followed by decreases in employment. On the other hand, an assessment of data collected and analyzed by David Neumark and William Wascher did not initially contradict the Card/Krueger results,[48] but in a later edited version they found that the same general sample set did increase unemployment. The 18.8% wage hike resulted in "[statistically] insignificant—although almost always negative" employment effects.[49]

Another possible explanation for why the current minimum wage laws may not affect unemployment in the United States is that the minimum wage is set close to the equilibrium point for low and unskilled workers. Thus in the absence of the minimum wage law unskilled workers would be paid approximately the same amount. However, an increase above this equilibrium point could likely bring about increased unemployment for the low and unskilled workers.[12]

Reaction to Card and Krueger

Some leading economists such as Greg Mankiw, Kevin M. Murphy and Nobel laureate Gary Becker do not accept the Card/Krueger results,[50][51] while some others, like Nobel laureates Paul Krugman[52] and Joseph Stiglitz do accept them as correct.[53][54] In 1995, the Republican Staff of the Joint Economic Committee of the United States Congress published a study critical of Card and Krueger's work. They note that it conflicts with other studies done on minimum wage laws within the United States over the past 50 years.[55] According to the JEC analysis, minimum wage laws have been shown to cause large amounts of unemployment, especially among low-income, unskilled, black, and teenaged populations, as well as cause a host of other mal-effects, such as higher turnover, less training, and fewer fringe benefits.

According to economists Donald Deere (Texas A&M), Kevin Murphy (University of Chicago), and Finis Weltch (Texas A&M), Card and Krueger's conclusions are contradicted by "common sense and past research". They conclude that:[56]

Each of the four studies examines a different piece of the minimum wage/employment relationship. Three of them consider a single state, and two of them look at only a handful of firms in one industry. From these isolated findings Card and Krueger paint a big picture wherein increased minimum wages do not decrease, and may increase, employment. Our view is that there is something wrong with this picture. Artificial increases in the price of unskilled laborers inevitably lead to their reduced employment; the conventional wisdom remains intact.

Nobel laureate James M. Buchanan responded to the Card and Krueger study in the Wall Street Journal, arguing:[57]

...no self-respecting economist would claim that increases in the minimum wage increase employment. Such a claim, if seriously advanced, becomes equivalent to a denial that there is even minimum scientific content in economics, and that, in consequence, economists can do nothing but write as advocates for ideological interests. Fortunately, only a handful of economists are willing to throw over the teaching of two centuries; we have not yet become a bevy of camp-following whores.

Alan Krueger responded in The Washington Post:[58]

More was at stake here than the minimum wage – the methodology of public policy analysis was also at issue. Some economists, such as James Buchanan, have simply rejected the notion that their view of economic theory possibly could be proved wrong by data.

Nobel laureate Paul Krugman, has argued in favour of the Card and Krueger result, stating that Card and Krueger;[59]

... found no evidence that minimum wage increases in the range that the United States has experiences led to job losses. Their work has been attacked because it seems to contradict Econ 101 and because it was ideologically disturbing to many. Yet it has stood up very well to repeated challenges, and new cases confirming its results keep coming in.

Neumark and Wascher

In a 2008 book, David Neumark and William L. Wascher described their analysis of over 300 studies on the minimum wage.[3] The studies were from several countries covering a period of over 50 years, primarily from the 1990s onward. According to the Neumark and Wascher, a large majority of the studies show negative effects for the minimum wage; those showing positive effects are few, questionable, and disproportionately discussed.

Based on the published studies they considered, Neumark and Wascher conclude that the minimum wage is not good social policy. They emphasize three especially salient conclusions: First, while acknowledging Card and Kreuger, they found that studies since the early 1990s have strongly pointed to a "reduction in employment opportunities for low-skilled and directly affected workers." Second, they found some evidence that the minimum wage is harmful to poverty-stricken families, and "virtually no evidence" that it helps them. Third, they found that the minimum wage lowers adult wages of young workers who encounter it, by reducing their ultimate level of education.

Statistical Meta-analyses

Several researchers have conducted statistical meta-analyses of the employment effects of the minimum wage. Card and Krueger analyzed 14 earlier time-series studies and concluded that there was clear evidence of publication bias because the later studies, which had more data and lower standard errors, did not show the expected increase in t-statistic (almost all the studies had a t of about two, just above the level of statistical significance at the .05 level).[60] Though a serious methodological indictment, opponents of the minimum wage virtually ignored this issue; as Thomas C. Leonard noted, "The silence is fairly deafening."[61] More recently, T.D. Stanley has criticized Card and Krueger's methodology, suggesting that their results could signify either publication bias or the absence of an effect. Using a different methodology, however, he concludes that there is statistically significant evidence of publication bias and that correction of this bias shows no relationship between the minimum wage and unemployment.[62] In 2008, Hristos Doucouliagos and T.D. Stanley conduct a similar meta-analysis of 64 U.S. studies on disemployment effects and concluded that Card and Krueger's initial claim of publication bias is still correct. Moreover, they concluded, "Once this publication selection is corrected, little or no evidence of a negative association between minimum wages and employment remains."[63]

Surveys of economists

Until the 1990s, economists generally agreed that raising the minimum wage reduced employment. This consensus was weakened when some well-publicized empirical studies showed the opposite, but others consistently confirmed the original view. Today's consensus, if one exists, is that increasing the minimum wage has, at worst, minor negative effects.[64]

According to a 1978 article in the American Economic Review, 90 percent of the economists surveyed agreed that the minimum wage increases unemployment among low-skilled workers.[65]

A 2000 survey by Dan Fuller and Doris Geide-Stevenson reports that of a sample of 308 American Economic Association economists, 45.6% fully agreed with the statement, "a minimum wage increases unemployment among young and unskilled workers", 27.9% agreed with provisos, and 26.5% disagreed. The authors of this study also reweighted data from a 1990 sample to show that at that time 62.4% of academic economists agreed with the statement above, while 19.5% agreed with provisos and 17.5% disagreed. They state that the reduction on consensus on this question is "likely" due to the Card and Krueger research and subsequent debate.[66]

A similar survey in 2006 by Robert Whaples polled PhD members of the American Economic Association. Whaples found that 37.7% of respondents supported an increase in the minimum wage, 14.3% wanted it kept at the current level, 1.3% wanted it decreased, and 46.8% wanted it completely eliminated.[67]

Surveys of labor economists have found a sharp split on the minimum wage. Fuchs et al. (1998) polled labor economists at the top 40 research universities in the United States on a variety of questions in the summer of 1996. Their 65 respondents split exactly 50-50 when asked if the minimum wage should be increased. They argued that the different policy views were not related to views on whether raising the minimum wage would reduce teen employment (the median economist said there would be a reduction of 1%), but on value differences such as income redistribution.[68] Klein and Dompe conclude, on the basis of previous surveys, "the average level of support for the minimum wage is somewhat higher among labor economists than among AEA members."[69]

In 2007, Daniel B. Klein and Stewart Dompe conducted a non-anonymous survey of supporters of the minimum wage who had signed the "Raise the Minimum Wage" statement published by the Economic Policy Institute. They found that a majority signed on the grounds that it transferred income from employers to workers, or equalized bargaining power between them in the labor market. In addition, a majority considered disemployment to be a moderate potential drawback to the increase they supported.[70]

Alternatives

Economists and other political commentators have proposed alternatives to the minimum wage. They argue that these alternatives may address the issue of poverty better than a minimum wage, as it would benefit a broader population of low wage earners, not cause any unemployment, and distribute the costs widely rather than concentrating it on employers of low wage workers.

Basic income

A basic income (or negative income tax) is a system of social security, that periodically provides each citizen with a sum of money that is sufficient to live on. Except for citizenship, a basic income is entirely unconditional. There is no means test, and the richest as well as the poorest citizens would receive it. A basic income is often proposed in the form of a citizen's dividend (a transfer payment from the government). Proponents argue that a basic income that is based on a broad tax base, would be more economically efficient, as the minimum wage effectively imposes a high marginal tax on employers, causing losses in efficiency.

In 1968 James Tobin, Paul Samuelson, John Kenneth Galbraith and another 1,200 economists signed a document calling for the US Congress to introduce in that year a system of income guarantees and supplements.[citation needed] Both Tobin and Samuelson have also come out against the minimum wage.[71] In the 1972 presidential campaign, Senator George McGovern called for a 'demogrant' that was very similar to a basic income.[72]

Winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics that fully support a basic income include Herbert Simon, Friedrich Hayek,[73] James Meade, Robert Solow, Milton Friedman,[74] Jan Tinbergen and James Tobin.[citation needed]

Guaranteed minimum income

A guaranteed minimum income is another proposed system of social welfare provision. It is similar to a basic income or negative income tax system, except that it is normally conditional and subject to a means test. Some proposals also stipulate a willingness to participate in the labor market, or a willingness to perform community services.

Refundable tax credit

A refundable tax credit is a mechanism whereby the tax system can reduce the tax owed by a household to below zero, and result in a net payment to the taxpayer beyond their own payments into the tax system. Examples of refundable tax credits include the earned income tax credit and the additional child tax credit in the U.S., and working tax credits and child tax credits in the UK. Such a system is slightly different than a negative income tax, in that the refundable tax credit is usually only paid to households that have earned at least some income.

The ability of the earned income tax credit to deliver a larger monetary benefit to poor workers at a lower cost to society was recently documented in a report by the Congressional Budget Office.[75]

Collective bargaining

Sweden is an example of a developed nation where there is no minimum wage that is required by legislation. Instead, minimum wage standards in different sectors are set by collective bargaining.

See also

References

  1. ^ a b c d e http://www.epi.org/content.cfm/issueguides_minwage Real Value of the Minimum Wage
  2. ^ Black, John (2003-09-18). Oxford Dictionary of Economics. Oxford University Press, USA. p. 300. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  3. ^ a b c d Neumark, David (2008). Minimum Wages. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. ISBN 978-0-262-14102-4. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  4. ^ a b c Eatwell, John, Ed. (1987). The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. London: The Macmillan Press Limited. pp. 476–478. ISBN 0-333-37235-2. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  5. ^ a b c d Sowell, Thomas (2007-04-02). Basic Economics (3rd Edition): A Common Sense Guide to the Economy. New York: Basic Books. ISBN 0-465-00260-9. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help) Minimum Wage Laws are covered on pages 210-221. The full text of an essentially identical section from a previous edition can be found at page 163 HERE
  6. ^ American Academy of Political and Social Science. "The Cost of Living." Philadelphia, 1913.
  7. ^ a b ILO 2006: Minimum wages policy (PDF)
  8. ^ Washington State Department of Labor and Industries, "Washington's minimum wage to increase to $8.55 Jan. 1," news release September 30, 2008, http://www.lni.wa.gov/news/2008/pr080930a.asp, consulted 29 December 2008.
  9. ^ "What are the current rates of the national minimum wage?", HM Revenue & Customs, http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/nmw/#b
  10. ^ a b David Card and Alan B. Krueger, Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage, Princeton University Press, 1995, pp. 1, 6-7.
  11. ^ Gwartney, James D. Economics: Private and Public Choice. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. pp. 559–562. ISBN 0-15-518880-1. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  12. ^ a b c d Ehrenberg, R. and Smith, R. "Modern labor economics: theory and public policy", HarperCollins, 1994, 5th ed.
  13. ^ William M. Boal and Michael R. Ransom, "Monopsony in the Labor Market", Journal of Economic Literature, V.35, March, pgs.86-112 [1]
  14. ^ P. Garegnani, "Heterogeneous Capital, the Production Function and the Theory of Distribution", Review of Economic Studies, V. 37, N. 3 (Jul. 1970): 407-436
  15. ^ Robert L. Vienneau, "On Labour Demand and Equilibria of the Firm", Manchester School, V. 73, N. 5 (Sep. 2005): 612-619
  16. ^ Michael Anyadike-Danes and Wyne Godley, "Real Wages and Employment: A Sceptical View of Some Recent Empirical Work", Machester School, V. 62, N. 2 (Jun. 1989): 172-187
  17. ^ Graham White, "The Poverty of Conventional Economic Wisdom and the Search for Alternative Economic and Social Policies", The Drawing Board: An Australian Review of Public Affairs, V. 2, N. 2 (Nov. 2001): 67-87
  18. ^ Gary Fields, "The Unemployment Effects of Minimum Wages," International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 15, issue 2 (1994), pp. 74-81.
  19. ^ Manning, Alan (2003). Monopsony in motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691113122. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  20. ^ Gillespie, Andrew (2007). Foundations of Economics. Oxford University Press. p. 240.
  21. ^ Alan S. Blinder, "The $5.15 Question," The New York Times, 23 May 1996, p. A29.
  22. ^ Harry Bernstein, "Troubling Facts on Employment," Los Angeles Times, September 15, 1992, p. D3; Eric Engquist, "Health Bill Fight Nears Showdown," Crain's New York Business, May 15, 2006, p. 1.
  23. ^ a b c Richard B. Freeman (1994). "Minimum Wages – Again!". International Journal of Manpower. {{cite journal}}: |access-date= requires |url= (help); Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  24. ^ a b OECD (2006): OECD Employment Outlook 2006 (read-only PDF)
  25. ^ Fiscal Policy Institute, "States with Minimum Wages Above the Federal Level have had Faster Small Business and Retail Job Growth," March 30, 2006.
  26. ^ Minimum Wage and Its Effects on Small Business
  27. ^ Abbott, Lewis F. Statutory Minimum Wage Controls: A Critical Review of their Effects on Labour Markets, Employment, and Incomes. ISR Publications, Manchester UK, 2nd. edn. 2000. ISBN 978-0-906321-22-5. [2]
  28. ^ Wal-Mart Warms to the State - Mises Institute
  29. ^ Wal-Mart's Perverse Strategy on the Minimum Wage
  30. ^ Tupy, Marian L. Minimum Interference, National Review Online, May 14, 2004
  31. ^ "The Wages of Politics". Wall Street Journal.
  32. ^ Offshoring High-Tech and Professional Jobs
  33. ^ Increasing the Mandated Minimum Wage: Who Pays the Price?
  34. ^ Why Wal-Mart Matters - Mises Institute
  35. ^ "Will have only negative effects on the distribution of economic justice. Minimum-wage legislation, by its very nature, benefits some at the expense of the least experienced, least productive, and poorest workers." (Cato)
  36. ^ Williams, Walter (1989). South Africa's War Against Capitalism. New York: Praeger. ISBN 027593179X. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  37. ^ a b c A blunt instrument, The Economist, October 26, 2006 Template:En icon
  38. ^ [3][4][5]
  39. ^ "National Minimum Wage". politics.co.uk. Retrieved 2007-12-29.
  40. ^ Metcalf, David (2007). "Why Has the British National Minimum Wage Had Little or No Impact on Employment?". {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |month= ignored (help)
  41. ^ Low Pay Commission (2005). National Minimum Wage - Low Pay Commission Report 2005
  42. ^ Edward M. Gramlich, "Impact of Minimum Wages on Other Wages, Employment, and Family Incomes," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Volume 1976, number 2, pp. 409-461.)
  43. ^ Charles Brown, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen "Time Series Evidence on the Effect of the Minimum Wage on Youth Employment and Unemployment," The Journal of Human Resources, Volume 18, no. 1 (Winter 1983), pp. 3-31.
  44. ^ Alison J. Wellington, "Effects of the Minimum Wage on the Employment Status of Youths: An Update," Journal of Human Resources, Volume 26, no. 1 (Winter 1991), pp. 27-46.
  45. ^ David Card and Alan B. Krueger, "Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania," American Economic Review, Volume 84, no. 4 (September 1994), pp. 774-775.
  46. ^ p. 792.
  47. ^ "Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage". Cato Institute. April 22, 2006.
  48. ^ http://www.epinet.org/briefingpapers/minimumw_bp_1996.pdf
  49. ^ Neumark & Wascher, American Economic Review, Volume 90 No. 5.
  50. ^ http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/2006/11/minimum-wage-as-symbol.html, consulted 12 January 2009.
  51. ^ Becker, Gary (1995-03-06). "IT'S SIMPLE: HIKE THE MINIMUM WAGE, AND YOU PUT PEOPLE OUT OF WORK". BusinessWeek. Retrieved 2009-07-09.
  52. ^ Paul Krugman, The conscience of a liberal (W.W. Norton & Co., 2007)
  53. ^ Joseph Stiglitz. Employment, social justice and societal well-being, International Labour Review, 141 (1-2), p. 9 - 29.
  54. ^ Economic Policy Institute. Hundreds of Leading Economists Say: Raise the Minimum Wage
  55. ^ U.S. Congress Joint Economic Committee "50 Years of Research on the Minimum Wage"
  56. ^ Sense and Nonsense on the Minimum Wage
  57. ^ "Minimum wage addendum". Wall Street Journal. 25-04-1996. pp. A20. {{cite news}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  58. ^ Alan Krueger, "Test Case for the Labor Market," The Washington Post, September 2, 1996, p. A23.
  59. ^ Paul Krugman, The Conscience of a Liberal, W.W. Norton, 2007, p. 261
  60. ^ David Card and Alan B. Krueger, "Time-series minimum-wage studies: a meta-analysis," American Economic Review 85: 238-243 (1995).
  61. ^ Thomas C. Leonard, "The Very Idea of Applying Economics: The Modern Minimum-Wage Controversy and its Antecedents," History of Political Economy 32 (1), p. 139 (2000).
  62. ^ T.D. Stanley, "Beyond Publication Bias, Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 19, no. 3 (2005), pp. 322-327.
  63. ^ Hristos Doucouliagos and T.D. Stanley, "Publication Bias in Minimum-Wage Research? A Meta-Regression Analysis," British Journal of Industrial Relations, 2008.
  64. ^ "A Blunt Instrument; The Minimum Wage," The Economist, October 28, 2006.
  65. ^ Kearl, J. R., et al., “A Confusion of Economists?” American Economic Review 69 (1979): 28–37.
  66. ^ Fuller, Dan (2003). "Consensus Among Economists: Revisited" (PDF). Journal of Economic Education. 34 (4): 369–387. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |month= (help); Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  67. ^ Robert Whaples (2006) "Do Economists Agree on Anything? Yes!," The Economists' Voice: Vol. 3 : Iss. 9, Article 1.
  68. ^ Victor R. Fuchs, Alan B. Krueger, and James M. Poterba, "Economists' Views About Parameters, Values, and Policies: Survey Results in Labor and Public Economics," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 36, no. 3 (September 1998), pp. 1387-1425.
  69. ^ Klein, Daniel and Stewart Dompe. "Reasons for Supporting the Minimum Wage: Asking Signatories of the "Raise the Minimum Wage" Statement" (Jan 2007), p. 133.
  70. ^ Klein, Daniel and Stewart Dompe. "Reasons for Supporting the Minimum Wage: Asking Signatories of the "Raise the Minimum Wage" Statement" (Jan 2007). [6]
  71. ^ Emerson Schmidt, "Union Power and the Public Interest", EP Dutton, 1980 as cited in [7]
  72. ^ White, Theodore H. The Making of the President 1972. Antheneum Publishers. 1973. pp. 17–20. ISBN 0689105533, pg. 127
  73. ^ Hayek, Friedrich (1973). Law, Legislation and Liberty: A New Statement of the Liberal Principles of Justice and Political Economy. Vol. 2. Routledge. p. 87. ISBN 071008403X.
  74. ^ Friedman, Milton (1990). Free to Choose: A Personal Statement. Harcourt. pp. 120–3. ISBN 0-15-633460-7. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  75. ^ "Consequences of an increase in the minimum wage and expansions in the earned income tax credit" (PDF). Congressional Budget Office. Retrieved 2008-07-25.