Jump to content

Infant industry argument

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
(Redirected from Infant industry effect)
Alexander Hamilton first codified the infant industry argument.

The infant industry argument is an economic rationale for trade protectionism.[1] The core of the argument is that nascent industries often do not have the economies of scale that their older competitors from other countries may have, and thus need to be protected until they can attain similar economies of scale. The logic underpinning the argument is that trade protectionism is costly in the short run but leads to long-term benefits.[1]

Early articulations

[edit]

The argument was first fully articulated by the first United States Secretary of the Treasury Alexander Hamilton in his 1790 Report on Manufactures. Hamilton professed that developing an industrial base in a country was impossible without protectionism because import duties are necessary to shelter domestic "infant industries" until they could achieve economies of scale.[2] The argument was systematically developed by American political economist Daniel Raymond,[3] and was later picked up by economist Friedrich List in his 1841 work The National System of Political Economy, following his exposure to the idea during his residence in the United States in the 1820s.[3] List criticized Britain for advocating free trade to other countries given that Britain had obtained its economic supremacy through high tariffs and government subsidies. List stated that "it is a very common clever device that when anyone has attained the summit of greatness, he kicks away the ladder by which he climbed up, in order to deprive others of the means of climbing up after him."[4]

1980s Brazil

[edit]

Infant industry protection is controversial as a policy recommendation. As with the other economic rationales for protectionism, it is often abused by rent seeking interests. In addition, countries that put up trade barriers to imports often face retaliatory barriers to their exports, potentially hurting the same industries that infant industry protection is intended to help. Even when infant industry protection is well-intentioned, it is difficult for governments to know which industries they should protect; infant industries may never grow up relative to adult foreign competitors. During the 1980s Brazil enforced strict controls on the import of foreign computers in an effort to nurture its own infant computer industry. This industry never matured; the technological gap between Brazil and the rest of the world actually widened, while the protected industries merely copied low-end foreign computers and sold them at inflated prices.[5]

Recommendation to the United Nations

[edit]

In his 2000 report to the UN Secretary-General, Ernesto Zedillo recommended "legitimising limited, time-bound protection for certain industries by countries in the early stages of industrialisation", arguing that "however misguided the old model of blanket protection intended to nurture import substitute industries, it would be a mistake to go to the other extreme and deny developing countries the opportunity of actively nurturing the development of an industrial sector".[6]

History of implementation

[edit]

According to economist Ha-Joon Chang, many countries have successfully industrialized behind tariff barriers, such as the United States and Britain.[7] From 1816 through 1945, tariffs in the United States were among the highest in the world.[3] Chang claimed that, "almost all of today's rich countries used tariff protection and subsidies to develop their industries".[8] A study[9] of French cotton producers during the Napoleonic Wars found that regions which were protected from international trade with Britain due to blockades of British shipping, experienced greater growth in mechanized cotton output than regions which continued to have close trade with Britain. Canada developed its infant industries, while facilitating the settlement of the Canadian West through immigration and railway construction under the National Policy (1879–1950s) following an earlier experiment in free trade with the United States. South Korea and Taiwan are more recent examples of rapid industrialization and economic development with major government subsidies, foreign exchange controls, and high tariffs to protect selected industries.[10][11] In Latin America, many countries have implemented economic policies which establish high tariffs and other barriers to international trade,[12] such as Brazil.[13] Many Latin American economists have contributed to the development of theories related to economic nationalism, which in turn promotes the protection of infant industries.[14]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b Oatley, Thomas (2019). International Political Economy: Sixth Edition. Routledge. pp. 139–144. ISBN 978-1351034647.
  2. ^ Paul Bairoch, "Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes," (1995: University of Chicago Press, Chicago) p. 33
  3. ^ a b c Chang, Ha-Joon. "Kicking Away the Ladder: How the Economic and Intellectual Histories of Capitalism Have Been Re-Written to Justify Neo-Liberal Capitalism" Archived 2019-10-25 at the Wayback Machine. Post-Autistic Economics Review. 4 September 2002: Issue 15, Article 3. Retrieved on 8 October 2008.
  4. ^ Ha-Joon Chang, "Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism," (New York: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2008), p. 16
  5. ^ Luzio, Eduardo (1996.) The microcomputer industry in Brazil: the case of a protected high-technology industry. Santa Barbara: Greenwood Publishing.
  6. ^ Zedillo, Ernesto (2000.) Technical Report of the High-Level Panel on Financing for Development. New York: United Nations.
  7. ^ Ha-Joon Chang, "Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism," (New York: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2008), p. 15
  8. ^ Chang, Ha-Joon (2002.) Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
  9. ^ Juhász, Réka. 2018. "Temporary Protection and Technology Adoption: Evidence from the Napoleonic Blockade." American Economic Review, 108 (11): 3339–76
  10. ^ Ha-Joon Chang, "Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and the Secret History of Capitalism," (New York: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2008), p. 14
  11. ^ Lee, Jaymin (1997-08-01). "The maturation and growth of infant industries: The case of Korea". World Development. 25 (8): 1271–1281. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(97)00035-1. ISSN 0305-750X.
  12. ^ "A Case Study of Infant Industry in Latin America". The Business History Review. 39 (4): 589–596. 1965. doi:10.2307/3112604. ISSN 0007-6805. JSTOR 3112604. S2CID 246480609.
  13. ^ "The country built on trade barriers". BBC News. 2018-08-01. Retrieved 2022-02-06.
  14. ^ "Peripheral Thoughts for International Political Economy: Latin American Ideational Innovation and the Diffusion of the Nineteenth Century Free Trade Doctrine". International Studies Quarterly. 61 (4): 924–934. 1965.